Preaching to the Choir: Coordinating Strategic Voting on Facebook During the 2018 Hungarian Election Campaign

Preaching to the Choir: Coordinating Strategic Voting on Facebook During the 2018 Hungarian Election Campaign

Peter Bence Stumpf
Copyright: © 2020 |Pages: 17
DOI: 10.4018/978-1-7998-0377-5.ch009
OnDemand:
(Individual Chapters)
Available
$37.50
No Current Special Offers
TOTAL SAVINGS: $37.50

Abstract

A main topic of the 2018 election campaign in Hungary was strategic voting, seen as an opportunity for opposition parties to remove the governing coalition from power. Strategic split-ticket voting was incentivized by the political context and the electoral system and was further facilitated by a limited cooperation between opposition political forces. Nonetheless, demand-side coordination was indispensable in this aspect. While social media was an important channel during the campaign, it was not crucial for strategic voting as it was mostly used to reinforce the positions of candidates among their own supporters, “preaching to the choir”. The influence of strategically split ballots can be measured in seat shares by modeling what would have happened if there was no coordination and cooperation at all. Results indicate that strategic votes transferred a total of 15 seats from the governing parties to the opposition political blocs, however this was not enough to prevent the decisive victory of the Fidesz-KDNP and another two-thirds supermajority in the Hungarian National Assembly.
Chapter Preview
Top

Theoretical Framework

This paper examines an overlap of several closely related but still separate phenomena and consequently it is based on a wide theoretical framework of strategic voting, split-ticket voting, voter coordination and the effects of social media on modern political campaigns. These were all influential factors during the 2018 Hungarian elections and their interplay greatly contributed to the final outcome. The expressions “strategic voting” and “tactical voting” will be used interchangeably in this paper. While the relevant literature mainly applies the term “strategic” to the voter behavior described here, “tactical” was used more often in Hungary recently. The distinction between the two could be made as the act of casting such a ballot is actually the tactic that is necessary to achieve a strategic goal like removing a party from government for example.

Strategic voting is defined as the choice made by a voter to move electoral support from the first-preferred party or candidate to another one because of the perception that the latter has a better chance at winning (Blais and Nadeau 1996). This is often called the “wasted-votes” theory and its central element is that voters want to influence the election outcome. At the same time there is an alternative explanation for switching the vote from the first-preference, according to which the electorate wants to influence the composition of governing coalitions (Gschwend 2007, Plescia 2017) and thus major party voters may support minor parties to achieve to desired configuration of seat shares. Such votes are often called strategic votes, ballots that contain the original first preference are on the other hand referred to as sincere votes. The concept of strategic voting is often traced back to Anthony Downs who described it mainly as a feature of multiparty systems in his seminal work, An economic theory of democracy (Downs 1957: 48). Switching one’s vote to a second-preferred candidate (or party) in a purely two-party context probably indicates indifference to the outcome and not strategic behavior. The theoretical basis of such conscious decisions obviously lies in a model that assumes voters are acting rationally and not expressively in the polling booth. This concept was further improved upon by Duverger with his idea that first-past-the-post systems produce two-party competition (Duverger 1954). To both generalize and operationalize this concept, one can describe a Duvergerian equilibrium, where all (rational) voters are always cast their ballots for the M + 1 candidates in a district with the magnitude of M (Crisp et al. 2012). There are two important realizations contained in this formalized version of Duverger’s law. First of all, that voters gravitate towards the viable contestants and desert unlikely winners. Second, as M is always specific to the district or constituency, that this mechanism is effective not on a national but on a constituency level.

Key Terms in this Chapter

Mixed-Member System: An electoral system where parties compete in majoritarian and proportional races simultaneously.

Hungary: Central-Eastern European country, member of the European Union.

SFPR Ratio: Another version of the SF ratio that uses party list vote counts in the proportional race instead of the candidate vote counts in the majority race.

Supply-Side Strategic Coordination: Cooperation of political groups regarding the nomination and withdrawal of candidates to facilitate strategic voting

Split-Ticket Voting: Casting different ballots simultaneously, splitting them between two or more separate political groups or candidates.

SF Ratio: A measure developed by Cox to measure strategic voting, it is the ratio of the second and first loser’s votes.

Strategic Voting: The decision by a voter to move electoral support from the first-preferred party or candidate to another one because of the perception that the latter has a better chance at winning.

Demand-Side Strategic Coordination: Voters defecting from first-preferred candidates in favor of viable contenders without any cooperation between the political parties.

Complete Chapter List

Search this Book:
Reset