Price Strategies in a Big Data World

Price Strategies in a Big Data World

Thierry Warin, Antoine Troadec
DOI: 10.4018/978-1-4666-9787-4.ch046
OnDemand:
(Individual Chapters)
Available
$37.50
No Current Special Offers
TOTAL SAVINGS: $37.50

Chapter Preview

Top

Introduction

This article presents the results of two empirical studies of price dispersion in homogenous goods markets separated by 10 years. The orthodox microeconomic literature explains that asymmetries of information in markets lead to an equilibrium in which price dispersion is present even when goods are perfectly homogenous. Therefore, with the advent of price comparison websites leading to a serious drop in search costs, firms should price their products at marginal cost. In a closer than ever pure and perfect competitive world, economic profits should disappear. Indeed, new information technologies make it easy to reduce asymmetric information for consumers.

Thanks to the Internet, research costs do not exist anymore. Everyone is able to go on different websites to compare the price of a laptop or a camera. However, empirical evidence shows that the real world is different. For a same item, a price may still vary through the week, or through the year. For instance, it is cheaper to buy a camera on Tuesday than on Friday.

Figure 1 illustrates the minimum price over time of a camera on the price aggregator Pricegrabber.com. The variation is interesting in the sense that it does not seem to follow a clear pattern, not even being steady around the usual equilibirum defined by price=marginal cost.

Figure 1.

Minimum price over time of a Canon EOS 5D Mark III Black SLR digital camera body on the website Pricegrabber.com, 1922 observations

978-1-4666-9787-4.ch046.f01
Source: Authors’ computations, 2015

Theory does not turn up. Why? The answer is that it is not only about the demand side, it is also about the supply side. To be more specific, if search costs are fairly low with the new communication technologies, so are the menu costs. Indeed, firms can change their prices very quickly at a very low cost as well. As a result they can use pricing strategies to re-gain some of their market power.

However, a question arises: with so many firms playing different pricing strategies, an incredible chaos in terms of volatility of prices should be expected. So, how can this chaos help firms benefit from a new market power? Well, the answer was proposed by Salop (1977) in a seminal paper with a concept coined “the noisy monopolist.” The general idea is that noise (in terms of prices) help create a monopolistic power.

However, although it is a very elegant theoretical result, it is tough to imagine that firms would create noise so that they might have a chance to randomly capture a minimal share of some consumer surplus. Well, in Game Theory, the Folk Theorem for dynamic games would help us find such a scenario. But beyond theory, in the real world, it would be interesting to see whether this strategy could be implemented. To prove it, it would require having access to huge amounts of data as well as great computing power. Well, with the access to big data, it is possible now to evaluate the practicality of the noisy monopolist concept.

In what follows, a comparison between a 2006 study and its replication in 2013-2014-2015 is proposed. The aim of these studies is to capture the new strategic model developed by companies in a high-technological day and age.

Top

Background

Information is vital for the fluidity of markets and was first highlighted by Akerlof (1970) in his seminal paper “The market for lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism.”

Following this article, Salop (1977) and Salop and Stiglitz (1977) proposed a theoretical framework that could explain price dispersion based on the cost of searching for the lower price. Varian (1980) proposed a study of “temporal price dispersion”, in which consumers can only be well-informed for short periods of time. The main reason is that firms have an interest to continually changer their prices.

While most research was purely theoretical in the past, the existence of the Internet and online gatekeepers has greatly facilitated the collection of data for empirical research. The first articles in this field were concerned with the comparison between online and traditional retail markets (Bakos, 1997).

Key Terms in this Chapter

Menu Cost: Cost, for the seller, associated with listing each item price, and changing this price through time.

E-Commerce: Trading in products or services happening on the Internet.

Big Data: Voluminous amount of structured, semi-structured and unstructured data that has potential to be mined for information.

Price Dispersion: Variation in prices across sellers of the same item.

Search Cost: Cost, for the customer, of acquiring information about a product and its price for the customer.

Price Gap: Price difference between the lowest two prices charged for a given good at a given time.

Market Thickness: Number of firms offering a given product.

Homogenous Goods: Products that vie with each other in a market but which have little or no differentiation in terms of features, benefits and quality.

Pricing: Method to set a selling price. The price mainly depends on demand and supply and can vary through time.

Value of Information: Amount than an informed consumer can expect to save by purchasing a given good at lowest price compared to an uniformed consumer, who can expect to pay the average price across all offers for the same good.

Complete Chapter List

Search this Book:
Reset