Institutions and Economic Policy

Institutions and Economic Policy

Paolo Ramazzotti
DOI: 10.4018/978-1-7998-4933-9.ch003
OnDemand:
(Individual Chapters)
Available
$37.50
No Current Special Offers
TOTAL SAVINGS: $37.50

Abstract

This chapter discusses the problems associated to an inadequate theory of economic policy. It begins by presenting the mainstream and heterodox approaches to policy. It contends that, according to the mainstream, policy must guarantee efficiency or, at the very least, consider it a key constraint, whereas according to heterodox economists, it may have a broader variety of goals. The latter's open system perspective implies that changes in the structure of the economy eventually feedback both on how people conceive of the economy and social welfare and on how the economy itself functions. The relevance of this issue, which is understated, emerges from the subsequent discussion of how neoliberal policies have changed the structure of the economy, the way people conceive of the economy, and even their voting behavior.
Chapter Preview
Top

Introduction

In late 2008, Queen Elisabeth II asked economists at the London School of Economics an embarrassing question: why nobody saw the financial crisis coming. The question was embarrassing from two points of view. First, it pointed out that many leading economists actually failed to understand what was going on at the time. Second, although the Queen presumably was unaware that some economists actually saw the crisis coming (e.g. Keen 1995; Minsky 1984), her question prompted another question: why did most economists disregard what their colleagues were foreseeing?

Both questions should have led to a reassessment of the (neoliberal) theories and practices that had dominated most economies during the previous decades. Counterintuitively, this did not happen. Albeit with a few exceptions – the most authoritative is Posner (2009) - most economists and policymakers did not question their views of the economy. Indeed, the situation was aptly depicted as “the strange non-death of neoliberalism” (Crouch 2011).

This situation raises various issues. Was the crisis an accident - a “black swan” - that policymakers and their economic consultants could hardly foresee, or was it determined by wrong policies? If policies were wrong, was it because of the theories that supported them? Considering the dramatic consequences the crisis led to, why did policymakers not change their economic consultants and why did voters in democratic countries not oust the policymakers that allowed the crisis to occur? Why were alternative perspectives on economic policy not convincing?

The aim of this chapter is to deal with these issues by contending that a major problem is the mechanistic and linear view that most economists have of economic policy. It does not expect to provide a full-fledged answer to all of the above questions. It nevertheless intends to frame them in what is likely to be a more fruitful way. Rather than dealing with specific models, it focuses on the assumptions and general theoretical frameworks that lie in the back of the minds of economists and that they, often unwittingly, tend to take for granted. In other terms, it focuses less on what they look at than on the “lenses” they use to look.

The standard approach to economic policy that emerges from most economics textbooks is that its aim is to deal with the shortcomings of the economy. Policymakers must understand what these shortcomings are and act upon them in order to achieve the best possible economic performance. The role of economic theory is to help them achieve this task. The problem they must face, however, is that different strands of economic thought provide distinct outlooks both on those shortcomings and on the effectiveness of public action. Most discussions about policy focus on which theory provides the best account for extant problems. It is generally understood, however, that once this issue is clear, it is possible to devise the appropriate measures.

The above approach to policy is based on a range of extremely restrictive assumptions, which, at the very least, need to be made explicit. They have to do with how the coordination of economic activities occurs. More specifically, mainstream economics – which, from the perspective of this chapter, includes the different strands of neoclassical economics along with Austrian economics – emphasizes the coordinating function of relative prices. Although it generally acknowledges that institutions must complement prices, the latter are what ultimately characterizes an economy. Policy must either allow prices to work properly or make up for their shortcomings.

Heterodox approaches provide a different outlook. Schools of thought, such as, amongst others, Original Institutional Economics, Post Keynesianism and Marxism share the view that, while prices are important, they can operate only as part of an institutional setup that is a prerequisite for their existence. Contrary to the mainstream, prices are not the means to assess economic performance.

The difference between the mainstream and heterodox approaches to economics may appear subtle but it has important implications for a proper understanding of the scope for policy, that is, its goals and its means. In particular, it allows for a reassessment of the notion of development. It suggests that the constraints to economic change vary significantly, depending on whether they are associated to markets or to historically determined institutions.

Key Terms in this Chapter

Heterox Economics: In this chapter it is an open systems approach as defined below.

Open/Closed Systems: A closed system, in this chapter, is a system that can function according to its own rules, independently of the rules of its surrounding environment. An economy conceived of as a closed system operates independently of the features of the society it is a part of. When society interferes with the rules of the economy, this appears as an exogenous shock. An open system, conversely, is one that interacts with its surrounding environment. When the economy is conceived of as an open system, society affects the rules of the economy and economy feeds back on the rules of society.

Institution: As pointed out in note 1, it is a system of established and embedded social rules that structures social interactions.

Collective Good: A good that meets the needs of a community as a whole. The community is viewed not as the mere sum of the individuals that comprise it but also as the outcome of their interaction.

Social: In general, it is something that relates to society. In a closed system perspective, it encompasses societal relations as opposed to strictly economic relations: consider the use of the term “social cost” in Coase 1988b. In an open system perspective, there is no clear boundary between society and the economy so that social includes both: consider the use of the term “social cost” in Kapp (2000) . In this chapter, whether the term is used according to one perspective or the other depends on the context.

Mainstream Economics: In this chapter it is a closed systems approach as defined below.

Complete Chapter List

Search this Book:
Reset